"not your garden variety economy" - richebacher

  1. dub
    33,892 Posts.
    lightbulb Created with Sketch. 350
    The Daily Reckoning PRESENTS: Why does America have the weakest recovery
    despite the most prodigious policy stimulus in history? If the economy's
    downturn was unique in its pattern, so also was the pattern of its upturn.
    The Good Doctor explores...

    NOT YOUR GARDEN VARIETY ECONOMY

    by Dr. Kurt Richebächer

    In short the 1920s were an era of world-wide credit expansion. Its most
    spectacular phase was the large-scale financing of inflated security and
    real estate values, especially in the United States. Such overcapitalised
    values were not reflected in the price level indices, which has generated
    confusion. Both Lauchlin Currie and Friedman and Schwartz have insisted,
    as have many others, that there was no inflation in the 1920s, since
    "prices" did not rise.
    - Melchior Palyi, The Twilight of Gold, 1914-1936, 1972

    Since Benjamin Bernanke's nomination by President Bush to succeed Alan
    Greenspan at the helm of the Federal Reserve, it has been widely reported
    that Bernanke had fixed his earlier professional career as a professor of
    economics upon the study of the cause or causes of the 1930s Great
    Depression, with the intent to make sure that this will never happen
    again.

    At a conference in 2002 honoring Milton Friedman's 90th birthday, he
    expressed contrition on behalf of the Federal Reserve: "Regarding the
    Great Depression, you are right, we [The Fed] did it. We are very sorry.
    But thanks to you, we won't do it again."

    Wondering about Mr. Bernanke's academic research, we took a closer look at
    his earlier writings and contemporary speeches. We learned that he did
    "groundbreaking research on how declining asset prices and weakened banks
    can choke off new lending and economic growth, and how the mistakes of the
    Federal Reserve compounded the catastrophe."

    America's Great Depression was by far the greatest economic and financial
    disaster in history. Yet it strikes us that the discussion in the United
    States has been stuck in the assertion that the Fed's failure to ease its
    reins fast enough was key to the savage asset and price deflation that
    followed during the 1930s.

    The question of what may have gone wrong during the prior boom to cause
    the Depression has always been discarded as beside the point, with the
    argument that the extraordinary price stability prevailing in the 1920s
    represented conclusive evidence of the absence of any inflationary
    influences.

    For most American economists, the verdict of Milton Friedman and A.J.
    Schwartz at the end of their Monetary History of the United States,
    1867-1960, published in 1963, about the causes of the Great Depression, is
    virtual dogma. And so it is for Mr. Bernanke. To quote Friedman:

    "The stock market boom and the afterglow of concern with World War I
    inflation have led to a widespread belief that the 1920s were a period of
    inflation and that the collapse from 1929-1933 were a reaction to that. In
    fact, the 1920s were, if anything, a time of relative deflation: From
    1923-1929 - to compare peak years of business cycles and to avoid
    distortions from cyclical influences - wholesale prices fell at the rate
    of 1% per year and the stock of money rose at the annual rate of 4% per
    year, which is roughly the rate required to match expansion of output. The
    business cycle expansion from 1927-1929 was the first since 1881-1893
    during which wholesale prices fell, even if only a trifle, and there has
    been none since.

    "The monetary collapse from 1929-1933 was not an inevitable consequence of
    what had gone on before. It was the result of the policies followed during
    those years. As already noted, alternative policies that could have halted
    the monetary debacle were available throughout those years. Though the
    Federal Reserve proclaimed that it was following an easy monetary policy,
    in fact, it followed an exceedingly tight monetary policy."

    The 1920s were, indeed, a period of extraordinary price stability. In
    particular, under the influence of Milton Friedman, it became axiomatic
    for American policymakers and economists that the Depression must
    consequently have had its causes in the policies pursued after the stock
    market crash. One of the consequences of this generally accepted verdict
    has been a total lack of interest to probe more deeply into the
    intricacies of the boom phase. As a result, knowledge about eventual
    abnormalities during this phase is generally abysmal, even among leading
    American economists.

    Actually, the Fed moved quite fast in light of earlier experience,
    slashing its discount rate from 6% to 2.5% within one year. The first
    steep fall of stock prices lasted little more than two weeks, from Oct. 24
    to Nov. 13, 1929, from where it sharply recovered until April 1930.

    After a pretty stable first half of 1930, during which stock prices
    rallied strongly, the economy suddenly slumped in the second half, even
    though the broad money supply had barely budged. To quote
    Joseph Schumpeter: "Business operations contracted in the midst of a
    plentiful supply of 'money.'"

    With the euphoria about a "New Era" for the U.S. economy still virulent
    after the stock market crash, a quick recovery was generally expected.
    What strikingly differentiated this downturn from all forerunners was the
    sudden, sharp slump in consumer spending. Yet it was taken for granted
    that the Fed's rapid rate cuts would usher in economic revival.

    A truly dramatic change in economic activity, and also in expectations,
    only began with the banking crisis of November-December 1930, acting to
    reduce the money supply. Escalating bank failures principally had their
    reason in declining market values of foreign, corporate and real estate
    bonds ravaging the banks' capital and lending power. The question is why
    asset prices fell - because of tight money or due to rising risk premiums
    as the quality of bonds began to be questioned?

    It is the great merit of the proponents of Austrian theory to have
    uncovered and shown that the borrowing and spending excesses driving a
    boom may, with or without inflation, exert harmful economic and financial
    effects other than just a rising inflation rate - actually, more harmful
    effects.

    In the postwar period, recessions in the industrialized countries were
    sharp and brief until the late 1970s. Limited spending excesses in
    inventories, business fixed investment, consumer durables and construction
    were liquidated within barely a year. In the United States, the typical
    recession for the postwar period has averaged one year, with a decline in
    real GDP by 2%. As soon as the Fed loosened its shackles, pent-up demand
    in the areas affected by credit restraint took off again, catapulting the
    economy to new heights.

    Sometime in early 2001, Mr. Greenspan expressed the view that the
    unfolding recession was of the harmless "garden-variety" type. This used
    to be the popular label for the short "cyclical" recessions that had been
    typical of the whole postwar period.

    Actually, the U.S. economy's downturn in 2001 had no relationship or
    similarity whatsoever to the customary "garden-variety" cycle. Credit
    growth, far from slowing down, accelerated as never before. An
    unprecedented slump in business fixed investment, plunging over the
    following eight quarters by 14.5%, acted as the single depressant.

    But sharp increases of other demand components, propelled by prodigious
    fiscal and monetary stimuli, soon more than offset the slump in business
    fixed investment. Government spending increased by 9.2% during the same
    eight quarters. In the private sector, the Fed-engineered housing bubble
    boosted residential building (+7.2%) and consumer spending (+6%). The net
    result was America's shallowest recession, but what followed was the
    slowest economic recovery in the postwar period. Could there be a
    connection between the two?

    Why the weakest recovery despite the most prodigious policy stimulus in
    history? If the economy's downturn was unique in its pattern, so also was
    the pattern of its upturn.

    By the third quarter of 2005, real GDP had grown 14.1% since 2000. It had
    accrued from disproportionate gains in residential building (+36.5%),
    consumption (+17.3%) and government spending (+16%). The major adverse
    counterbalancing forces were sluggish business investment (+5.9%) and
    soaring imports (+23%).

    Over the whole period, real GDP has grown at an annual rate of 2.9%. That
    is well below the average growth rate of 3.8% for previous postwar
    business cycles. Outright dramatic is the shortfall in employment and
    inflation-adjusted income growth. With all the phantom jobs from the "net
    birth/death," private sector jobs are just 1% higher than in December
    2000, for which employment for defense spending played a significant role.
    For comparison, payroll jobs in past cycles have risen about 9% over the
    same time.

    Essentially, this dramatic shortfall in employment implies a corresponding
    shortfall in income growth. During the three months to November 2005, real
    disposable incomes of private households exceeded their year-ago level by
    just 1.36%, as against 3.4% for real GDP.

    Mr. Greenspan and other Fed members have never made a secret of their
    systematic efforts to create a panoply of new asset bubbles after the
    equity bubble popped. Among their policy novelties was the repetitive
    public assurance to keep their short-term policy rate at a rock-bottom
    level for as far as the eye can see as incentive for carry trade,
    particularly for long-term bonds, and as the key condition for inflating
    asset prices.

    Enraptured financial institutions promptly obliged by driving long-term
    rates and credit spreads to record lows through heavily leveraged carry
    trade. For the consensus, this represented a highly successful monetary
    policy that had bowed to no rules.

    In hindsight, they hail the many achievements: enormous "wealth creation"
    through rising house prices, record-high productivity growth, stable and
    comparatively strong economic growth and the mildest postwar recession in
    the wake of the bursting equity bubble in 2001.

    It makes an impressive list - only a very incomplete one. It ignores a
    variety of economic and financial inflictions causing and reflecting
    extremely unbalanced economic growth. This negative list begins with the
    savings collapse and the monstrous trade gap, and it continues with the
    housing bubble and the surge of consumption as a share of GDP. Last but
    not least, it must be taken into account that this subpar economic and
    income growth has involved an unprecedented credit and debt orgy.

    Regards,

    Dr. Kurt Richebächer
    for The Daily Reckoning

    P.S. With the general focus very strongly on the low core inflation rate,
    Mr. Greenspan earned a reputation for being America's greatest inflation
    fighter, which, in turn, is supposed to have laid the foundation for the
    stellar rate of productivity growth and the extraordinary steadiness of
    economic growth.


    Unfortunately, our economy's "growth" is a matter of smoke and mirrors.
    The government works feverishly to cover up the true statistics for things
    like inflation and employment...but I have the real data for you right
    here - and the real numbers completely blow the American prosperity and
    productivity myth out of the water:

    You've Been Fooled
    http://www1.youreletters.com/t/338039/10323665/784608/0/

    Editor's Note: Former Fed Chairman Paul Volcker once said: "Sometimes I
    think that the job of central bankers is to prove Kurt Richebächer wrong."
    A regular contributor to The Wall Street Journal, Strategic Investment and
    several other respected financial publications, Dr. Richebächer's
    insightful analysis stems from the Austrian School of economics. France's
    Le Figaro magazine has done a feature story on him as "the man who
    predicted the Asian crisis."


    dub

    Taken from today's The Daily Reckoning e-mail (which is free to all)
 
arrow-down-2 Created with Sketch. arrow-down-2 Created with Sketch.